European Economy

Banks, Regulation, and the Real Sector

  • Home
  • What is EE
  • Who is Who
    • Editorial Board
    • Scientific Advisory Board
    • Contributors
    • Association Friends of EE
  • ISSUES
  • Events
  • PRESS

Howard Davies

Howard Davies is chairman of the board of directors of Inigo Insurance. Until April 2024 he chaired the NatWest Group. Howard chaired the British Government's Airport Policy Review up to July 2015. He was previously the Director of the London School of Economics and Political Science from 2003 until May 2011. Prior to this appointment he was chairman of the UK Financial Services Authority from 1997 to 2003.
From 1995 to 1997 he was Deputy Governor of the Bank of England, after three years as the Director General of the Confederation of British Industry. Earlier in his career he worked in the Foreign and Commonwealth Office, the Treasury, McKinsey and Co, and as Controller of the Audit Commission.
He was an independent Director of Morgan Stanley Inc. from 2004- 15, and chaired the Risk Committee. He also chaired the Risk Committee at Prudential plc between 2010 and 2020. He is a member of the Regulatory and Compliance Advisory Board of Millennium Management LLC, a New York-based hedge fund. He has also been a member of the International Advisory Council of the China Banking Regulatory Commission since 2003 and since 2012 has been Chairman of the International Advisory Council of the China Securities Regulatory Commission. As of December, last year he is also chairman of Inigo Ltd.

Central Bank Digital Currency: An Idea Whose Time Has Come, or a Dangerous Misstep?

November 14, 2024 by Howard Davies

Authors

Howard Davies[1]Chair of the Natwest Group. Professor at Sciences Po, Paris.

 

Florida Governor Ron de Santis, not a regular commentator on technological developments in the payments system, has a clear view on the notion of a Federal Reserve sponsored digital dollar. In March 2023 he announced legislation ‘to protect Floridians from a Federally-controlled Central Bank Digital Currency (CBDC) and Surveillance State’[2]Governor Ron de Santis announces legislation to protect Floridians from a Federally-controlled Central Bank Digital Currency and Surveillance State. 20 March 2023 www.flgov.com. The CBDC, he proclaimed, is ‘the most recent way the Davos elites are attempting to backdoor woke ideology into the US financial system.’

The source of his concern is that once the Fed can oversee all consumer spending, it will be a short step to banning some transactions: ‘You go and use too much gas, they’re gonna stop it… you wanna go buy a rifle they’re gonna say no.’[3]De Santis on fed digital currency. www.tampabay.com 16 April 2023. Others on the right of US politics have made rather more sophisticated points with a similar import. The Cato Institute have argued that a CBDC would ‘threaten financial privacy and financial freedom, and undermine the banking and cryptocurrency industries.’ According to a survey they conducted, only 16 per cent of Americans support its introduction.[4]Only 16% of Americans support the government issuing a CBDC.’ 31 May 2023 www.cato.org.

At the other end of the political spectrum, the oversight powers a CBDC could give the central bank is seen as one of its key attractions. The head of the People Bank of China’s digital currency research institute, Mu Chang Chun, has emphasised the attraction of a digital currency for combatting financial crime, arguing that the authorities can ‘use big data and data mining technology and conduct identity comparisons, we will be able to find the culprits[5]Quoted in ‘China’s proposed digital currency more about policing than progress.’ Brenda Goh and Samuel Shen. 1 November 2019 www.reuters.com..’ Civil liberties concerns do not loom large in their thinking.

In pressing ahead with plans for digital currencies central banks have stirred up a hornet’s nest, and not only at the extremities of the political marketplace. The UK House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee has taken an interest in the Bank of England’s plans. Their report concluded that they had ‘yet to hear a convincing case’ for a retail CBDC.[6]Central bank digital currencies: House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee report. 30 January 2023 www.lordslibrary.parliament.uk. They concluded that the idea was ‘a solution in search of a problem.’ An analysis prepared for the Econ committee of the European Parliament reached a similar conclusion. Its authors were ‘doubtful on the wisdom of eventually launching a digital euro (Angeloni, 2023).’

So why are central bankers around the world, with varying degrees of enthusiasm, embarking on this hazardous journey, at a time when their credibility is low after a period when inflation soared well above their targets. Perhaps a single-minded focus on rebuilding a reputation for sound financial management would have been a preferable strategy?

The most obvious answer is that cash usage is in decline, and in some places paper currency may disappear before too long. Try buying a beer in Stockholm with a 100 kroner bill. Though your money may be good, you will go thirsty: almost no retail outlets in Sweden accept cash of any kind. The volume of cash in circulation is falling fast, indeed has almost halved in the last decade. Switch, a mobile payment system introduced in 2012 by a consortium of banks, dominates the market. It has 8 million users: the Swedish population is little over 10 million.

But Sweden is an outlier. In the UK there is £80 billion of sterling cash in circulation, and the quantum has continued to rise, albeit more slowly than before. In the Eurozone the volume of cash outstanding has only just begun to drop back, albeit very slowly. In the US there is $2.25 trillion in issue, though much of it is held outside the States, especially in higher denomination notes. There is no sign of a decline, though spending a $100 bill in New York is close to impossible unless – or so I am told – you are buying recreational drugs. So in most countries reports of the death of cash as a store of value are exaggerated, though it is true that the proportion of transactions carried out in physical form is declining almost everywhere. In the UK, as an example, over the last decade cash-based transactions have fallen from 21 billion a day to 7 billion, while debit card transactions have risen from 2.3 billion to 7.5 billion.

The second stimulus for the central bank work on CBDCs came from the company formerly known as Facebook.

At the end of each year’s IMF/World Bank autumn meetings the Group of 30 organise a private session for central bankers and bankers. It is often the most informative meeting of the week. I well recall the session in October 2019 at which Facebook were invited to present their plans for a stablecoin, then known as Libra. Their representative explained that Facebook’s aim was financially to enfranchise the poor of the planet and quickly to replace the world’s fiat currencies. Digitally facilitated commerce would migrate to their own platform. The underlying message was that the central banks’ time as managers of the global money supply was coming to an end and that, frankly, Facebook would do a better job for us all. They would, incidentally, make a huge amount of money from what would in effect be interest-free loans from the population – which is what a dollar bill amounts to – but that advantage was not a declared part of the pitch.

The central bank Governors in the front row could see their seigneurage income, which keeps them in the style to which they have become accustomed, disappearing before their eyes. Their sinews stiffened, and they decided to fight back. Benoit Coeuré of the ECB threatened that ‘the bar set for regulatory approval will be very high.’ He described the Libra announcement as ‘a wake-up call’ and called for the ECB to ‘step up its thinking on a central bank digital currency[7]Spooked by Facebook’s Libra, euro zone to step up work on public crypto currency. 13 September 2019. www.saudigazette.’.

The subsequent demise of Libra was not a surprise. Facebook tried in a number of countries to secure regulatory approval for it and failed. After a time it was renamed Diem, to confuse the enemy, but the regulators were unmoved. In the end Facebook accepted defeat and in January 2022 sold the technology (which the central banks in fact regarded as intelligent and well-designed) to a Californian bank called Silvergate, which itself collapsed in March 2023. (One of its high profile clients was FTX).[8]Facebook ditches Diem stablecoin with asset sale to Silvergate, Roman Dillet. 27 January 2022. www.techcrunch.com

Diem was, therefore, never launched, and has become a footnote in the history of cryptocurrencies. But the work it triggered in the central banking community has continued: the Governors in Basel had glimpsed the future, and did not like what they saw. So they set their technologists to work.
The Bank for International Settlements has been assiduous in tracking CBDC activity around the world. Their 2022 survey, published in July 2023 (Kosse and Mattei, 2023) showed that 94 percent of all respondent central banks were working on a CBDC. Perhaps surprisingly, in view of the political sensitivities, the 2023 survey showed that ‘Work on retail CBDC is more advanced than on wholesale CBDC.’

Almost a quarter of central banks were piloting a retail version and the BIS forecast that there would be 15 retail currencies circulating by 2030. So even though, in almost all cases, there have been no changes in the law to facilitate such issuance and no formal political support for it, central banks were pressing ahead, on the unstated assumption that the privacy and competition issues can easily be resolved.

That may be a heroic assumption, and even some central bankers have acknowledged that they have not so far succeeded in winning over public or political opinion. The Governor of the Austrian central bank, Robert Holtzmann, has recognised that ‘what is still missing is a convincing storyline for the digital euro, something which we can put in front of the people’.[9]Digital euro conspiracy theories and privacy concerns put EU central bankers in the hot seat. Jack Schikler, Coindesk. 11 September 2023. www.sg.news.yahoo.com. EU Commissioner Mairead McGuiness, who put plans to approve the e-euro to the European Parliament last year, has now backtracked, telling MPs that ‘there is no pressure on parliament or council to finish this piece of legislation… I think slowing down is a very healthy thing.’

Part of the reason for this growing reticence among policy-makers is that the central banks have found it challenging to defend their plans against the charge that a CBDC may threaten financial stability. It is widely accepted now that it would need to be delivered through commercial banks: central banks have balked at the prospect of opening millions of accounts for private citizens. They are simply not equipped to do so. (When I was the Deputy Governor of the Bank of England in the 1990’s staff members could hold accounts there: persuading your local curry house to accept a Bank of England cheque was quite a problem, and there were only two ATMs – at head office, and the Bank’s printing works – that would accept it.)

But if every account-holder at a private sector bank has a central bank wallet on their mobile phone in addition to their current account, a bank run is just a click away. A speculative social media rumour about the health of a bank could trigger an instant reaction. The failure of Silicon Valley Bank last year showed how quickly a bank run can now develop. And the second order consequences could be very significant. If a commercial bank lost customer deposits rapidly the central bank, as regulator, would need very quickly to decide whether the problem was one of liquidity or solvency. If the bank is insolvent, the central bank would need to put it into resolution very quickly. But if the central bank concluded that the bank affected by the run was fundamentally viable, it would need to redeposit those transferred funds with the illiquid bank, quickly becoming its largest source of funds: an uncomfortable position for a regulator to be in. And it might take a long time for that position to be unwound.

In its own analysis of the potential impact of a CBDC, the Federal Reserve has acknowledged these concerns (Carapella et al., 2024). The Fed recognises that banks ‘might suffer larger or more frequent runs in the presence of a CBDC’, and furthermore that ‘a CBDC may weaken financial stability by reducing the ability of banks to extend credit at times of stress.’ Their conclusion is that in stress times the rates charged to borrowers ‘may increase by 50 to 250 basis points,’ and that lending to corporates may reduce by between 1 and 5%. The percentage is not huge, but would be material. They recommend that central banks should attempt to reduce the attractiveness of a CBDC, by adopting a model in which CBDC holdings do not attract interest, and by imposing holding limits. The ECB has proposed that there should be a €3,000 euro limit on any individual holding a digital euro account backed by the central bank.

Controls of that kind would certainly help to mitigate the financial stability risks. The prohibition on internet payments on CBDC is uncontroversial, as cash does not generate a return (except perhaps in the unusual case where deposit rates at the central bank turn negative). But a holding limit would make a CBDC fundamentally different from the cash it purports to replace. There are no holding limits on bank notes – through putting a large volume of cash back into the banking system may be a challenge for anti-money laundering reasons. So solving the financial stability problems may come at the expense of one of the principles on which the case for a CBDC is founded. The more you offset the financial stability risks the less perfect a substitute for cash the CBDC becomes.

With a low holding limit, as proposed by the ECB, the CBDC looks like a safety valve which would close, rather than open, when the system is under pressure – an odd concept. So why are some central banks still keen to press ahead?

The Bank of England has tried harder than most to construct an intellectually coherent argument. It presents the primary case for a digital pound as being to ensure ‘the role of UK central bank money as an anchor for confidence and safety in our monetary system’ (H.M Treasury and the Bank of England, 2023), with a secondary argument that it will promote ‘innovation, choice and efficiency in payments.’ Note that the case advanced by Facebook, that a global stablecoin was needed to reduce the cost of cross-border payments, has now been relegated to a list of ‘other motivations’.

By no means all central banks are persuaded of the merits of these arguments. Randy Quarles, the former Deputy Chairman of the Fed, is a prominent opponent. ‘CBDCs, he argues, are driven by FOMO (Fear of Missing Out) and vulnerability to mass suspension of our critical thinking and to impetuous deluded crazes and fads’.[10]Fed’s Quarles compares CBDC rush to parachute pants and FOMO. 28 June 202. www.pymnts.com. Stephen Cecchetti, the former Chief Economist of the BIS, argues that a rash of CBDCs will not improve the global payments system, and could result in a ‘bad equilibrium’ where ‘a world of multiple CBDCs in advanced economies threaten financial stability domestically.’ He argues, furthermore, that a CBDC cannot be anonymous, to avoid facilitating criminal activity, and that a tight holding limit makes no sense as, if one were imposed ‘there would be circumstances when bank liabilities will not be convertible into CBDC at par’ (Schoenholtz and Cecchetti, 2021). In attempting to respond to financial stability and privacy concerns, the central banks have produced a camel: a horse designed by a committee.

Others point out that there is no shortage of innovative private sector developments in the payments system. Facebook’s world-conquering model may have been a bridge too far, but stablecoins are developing rapidly and the cost of cross-border payments is falling. India provides an example of how a Unified Payments Interface, stimulated by the government through the creation of nationwide digital identifiers, can bring digital payments to a huge proportion of the population, with no need for a CBDC.[11]A digital payment revolution in India. 15 May 2023. The Economist www.economist.com.

But perhaps, in the deepest recesses of the central banks’ vaults, there are other arguments in play. In particular, there is a difficult question of monetary sovereignty in a world in which cash disappears – though that day is a long way off in most countries, as we have seen. The Fed hints at some concerns in its own discussion paper on a digital dollar, which is in other respects less forthcoming and enthusiastic than similar papers from the ECB. They note that a potential benefit of a CBDC ‘could be to preserve the dominant international role of the US dollar,’ raising the spectre of a world in which other CBDCs might be ‘more attractive than existing forms of the US dollar’, so that ‘global use of the dollar could decrease’.[12]Money and Payments: the US in the age of digital transformation. January 2022. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. www.federalreserve.org.

The ECB’s concerns are slightly different. They have become anxious about the US tendency to ‘weaponise’ the dollar payments system, by excluding countries from it through their sanctions regime. In the case of Russia, in the light of the war in Ukraine, US and EU interests have been aligned, so far, but that has not always been the case in relation to Iran, for example. There could well be other examples of non-aligned foreign policies in the future. Perhaps a digital euro would create a way round that potential problem? That may be behind the ECB’s claim that a digital euro would ‘safeguard monetary sovereignty’ (Panetta, 2022).

 

Conclusion

The world’s central banks have, in the last five years, devoted considerable resources to projects designed to produce a proof of concept for a CBDC. Some have gone so far as to pilot a live version. The Peoples Bank of China has done so in 4 cities, and has announced a partnership with the Singaporean authorities to allow the e-CNY to be used there. Three Caribbean countries have launched CBDCs, though a recent review by the Kansas City Fed concluded that ‘a few years after launching, none of the Caribbean CBDCs had yet achieved widespread adoption’.[13]Observations form the Retail CBDCs of the Caribbean. Franklin Noll. Kansas City Fed. 10 April 2024. www.kansascityfed.org.

And so far none of the major Western central banks have made a firm commitment to go ahead. The Fed’s declared position is that they will not move forward without specific legislative approval, which seems unlikely to be forthcoming in the near future. Most Republican elected officials are instinctively hostile, even if they are not all as vocal as Governor De Santis. And the EU Commission and Parliament, who were moving towards legislation last year, have applied the brakes, at least temporarily.

In these circumstances it may be wise for the central banks themselves to act cautiously. After the last two years when their credibility has taken a hit while inflation soared, they do not need another failure, or to enter the highly controversial territory of civil liberties and privacy. There is a far stronger case today for a wholesale CBDC, which raises fewer concerns among politicians and the public. Indeed there are signs that the market for a wholesale CBDC is beginning to open up. In June 2024 the World Bank issued its first Swiss Franc digital bond. It uses distributed ledger technology and settles using a Swiss Franc wholesale central bank digital currency from the Swiss National Bank.[14]World Bank to issue CHF Digital Bond settled using Swiss Franc CBDC. 19 May 2024. www.newsbitcoin.com.

Bruegel, the Brussels think tank, have set out the advantages of beginning with a wholesale euro. They argue that consumers in the eurozone benefit already from a very efficient retail payment system, and that ‘creating a CBDC for retail purposes in the euro area offers little obvious added value, at least for the foreseeable future’ (Demertzis and Martins, 2023), whereas they see a strong case for building a digital currency that can be used for wholesale cross-country payments. Central banks could then settle directly with each other, rather than via the US dollar, which is often the case today. As they point out, since banks already have accounts at the central bank, a wholesale CBDC ‘does not need to be created from scratch’.

The most recent BIS survey shows that at least some central banks are coming round to that view (Di Iorio et al., 2024), in June 2024 they noted that over the last year, the emphasis has changed, and the BIS conclude that ‘the likelihood that central banks will issue a wholesale CBDC within the next six years now exceeds the likelihood that they will issue a retail CBDC.’

Starting with a wholesale euro would be a practical, useful step the ECB could take. It would not be front page news, perhaps, but central banking is not a popularity contest, and a retail CBDC raises many issues which have yet to be addressed. Wholesale discretion may be the better part of valour in today’s political climate.

 

References

Angeloni, I. (2023). Digital Euro: when in doubt, abstain. Economic Governance and EMU Scrutiny Unit. April 2023. Available at: www.europarl.europa.eu.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2022). Money and Payments: the US in the age of digital transformation. January 2022. Available at: https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/files/money-and-payments-20220120.pdf.

Carapella, F., Chang, J.W., Infante, S., Leistra, M., Lubis, A., and Vardoulakis, A.P. (2024). Financial Stability Implications of CBDC. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2024-021. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2024.021.

Demertzis, M., and Martins, C. (2023). The value added of central bank digital currencies: a view from the euro area Policy brief 13/23. June 2023. Available at: www.bruegel.org.

Di Iorio, A., Kosse, A., and Ilaria Mattei, I. (2024). Embracing diversity, advancing together – Results of the 2023 BIS survey on central bank digital currencies and crypto. BIS paper 147. 14 June 2024. Available at: https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap147.htm.

H.M Treasury and the Bank of England. (2023). The digital pound: a new form of money for households and businesses. February 2023. Available at: www.bankofengland.co.uk.

Kosse, A., and Ilaria Mattei, I. (2023). Making headway – Results of the 2022 BIS survey on central bank digital currencies and crypto. BIS Papers No 136.10 July 2023. Available at: https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap136.htm.

Panetta, F. (2022). US Monetary Policy Forum. New York 18 February 2022. Available at: www.bis.org.

Schoenholtz, K., and Cecchetti, S. (2021). Central bank digital currency: the battle for the soul of the financial system. 8 July 2021. Centre for Economic Policy Research. Available at: https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/central-bank-digital-currency-battle-soul-financial-system.

Footnotes[+]

Footnotes
↑1 Chair of the Natwest Group. Professor at Sciences Po, Paris.
↑2 Governor Ron de Santis announces legislation to protect Floridians from a Federally-controlled Central Bank Digital Currency and Surveillance State. 20 March 2023 www.flgov.com.
↑3 De Santis on fed digital currency. www.tampabay.com 16 April 2023.
↑4 Only 16% of Americans support the government issuing a CBDC.’ 31 May 2023 www.cato.org.
↑5 Quoted in ‘China’s proposed digital currency more about policing than progress.’ Brenda Goh and Samuel Shen. 1 November 2019 www.reuters.com.
↑6 Central bank digital currencies: House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee report. 30 January 2023 www.lordslibrary.parliament.uk.
↑7 Spooked by Facebook’s Libra, euro zone to step up work on public crypto currency. 13 September 2019. www.saudigazette.
↑8 Facebook ditches Diem stablecoin with asset sale to Silvergate, Roman Dillet. 27 January 2022. www.techcrunch.com
↑9 Digital euro conspiracy theories and privacy concerns put EU central bankers in the hot seat. Jack Schikler, Coindesk. 11 September 2023. www.sg.news.yahoo.com.
↑10 Fed’s Quarles compares CBDC rush to parachute pants and FOMO. 28 June 202. www.pymnts.com.
↑11 A digital payment revolution in India. 15 May 2023. The Economist www.economist.com.
↑12 Money and Payments: the US in the age of digital transformation. January 2022. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. www.federalreserve.org.
↑13 Observations form the Retail CBDCs of the Caribbean. Franklin Noll. Kansas City Fed. 10 April 2024. www.kansascityfed.org.
↑14 World Bank to issue CHF Digital Bond settled using Swiss Franc CBDC. 19 May 2024. www.newsbitcoin.com.

Filed Under: 2024

The European Banking Union: Challenges Ahead

April 27, 2021 by Howard Davies

Authors

Howard Davies [1]Chair of the Natwest Group. Professor at Sciences Po, Paris.

 

“This time the banks are not part of the problem, as was the case in the financial crisis of 2008, but part of the solution” [2]Dividend payouts and share buybacks of global banks. ECB Financial Stability Review. May 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu . Such was the verdict of Felix Hufeld, then the President of the Bafin, the German financial regulator, in June 2020.

Hufeld himself has since moved on, a casualty of the Wirecard scandal, but his sentiment has been echoed by many regulators, commentators, and even some politicians who have been sparing in their praise of the banking sector in the past. It has even become something of a cliché, beloved of bankers themselves, who have enjoyed basking in the warmth of unaccustomed praise.

Bankers are human too (at least they like to think they are), so congratulations are always welcome, but some have been uncomfortably aware that these golden opinions may have come at a hefty price. Banks have been strongly encouraged, even required, to keep their branches open through the Covid lockdowns even when the footfall has been very light. They have given extended mortgage holidays to personal borrowers on demand. And they have extended loans to distressed companies, to help them through dips in demand, or even enforced closures. Some of those loans have been fully or partly guaranteed by governments, but it would be unrealistic to assume that the banks will not incur major losses on that and other lending. Some have been pushed into loss for 2020. And these losses come at a time when bank profitability is under serious threat from very low, or even negative interest rates. With yields on low risk assets almost flat as far as the analyst’s eye can see, the usual attractive and rewarding banking business of maturity transformation on an upwardly sloping curve has not been available.

That banks have survived this very difficult period can largely be attributed to the strong capital ratios they displayed when the crisis hit. Regulators have therefore taken some credit for the banks’ success. The aggressive re-regulation of the sector since 2008, led by the Basel Committee, has paid off. In spite of the sharpest recession for a century in the largest European economies, no significant bank has fallen over, or needed to be rescued by the state. And banks demonstrated remarkable operational resilience. The ECB acknowledges that there was no noticeable rise in operational losses due to business disruption or system failures. That is as remarkable as the strong capital position.

But in spite of this robust performance at a very challenging time the market has drawn the unsurprising conclusion that future profitability is uncertain and that bank stocks are to be treated with great care. Most large European banks have continued to trade at a significant discount to book value, well below 100% and systematically below their US counterparts in most cases, even though there was something of a rally in early 2021 (1).

Some might be tempted to think that if this is what it means to be a solution, maybe being a problem was not such a bad thing after all.

As we emerge from what we must hope to have been the worst of the pandemic, it is time to ask whether, from the banks’ perspective, anything has changed. Will politicians and regulators conclude that large banks, which many saw as dinosaurs, ready to be wiped out by agile digital fintech newcomers, or by the BigTech monoliths, have their social uses after all, and should not be allowed to vanish into the primeval swamp along with diesel engine plants and high street fashion retailers? Or will the Covid crisis be seen merely as a temporary respite in a process of secular decline?

To attempt an answer to that question we need to parse it a little, and address four sub-questions:

  1. Can we expect the regulatory environment to change as a result, in ways that might benefit traditional banks?
  2. Might the experience of the crisis, and the solidity the banks displayed, affect customer behaviour, and create a kind of ‘flight to safety’?
  3. Has the crisis weakened some new competitors and demonstrated weaknesses in their business models?
  4. Are banks therefore now in a stronger competitive position, or is their predicament fundamentally unchanged?

 

1. Regulation

The European regulators’ initial response to the Covid crisis was not encouraging from a bank perspective. In March 2020 both the European Central Bank and the Bank of England imposed restrictions on bank dividends, indeed they effectively banned any capital distributions during the whole of the year, to retain as much capital as possible within the banking system. The Federal Reserve did not take the same line, allowing normal dividends, typically accrued quarterly in the US, to continue, but did impose a moratorium on share buybacks, which in recent years have dominated US bank distributions.

The banks reacted negatively, arguing that their capital positions were strong enough to sustain normal dividends, and that preventing them from rewarding their shareholders would adversely affect investors’ views of the investability of bank stocks, thereby raising their cost of capital in the longer term. They pointed out that the ban was also inconsistent with the capital framework put in place since the crisis, with its higher ratios, buffers and rigorous stress tests.

By early 2021 there were signs that the regulators were beginning to soften their position, and allowing modest distributions to go ahead. The Bank of England revised its guidelines. The ECB allowed stronger banks to resume dividends within strict limits, noting that the average tier 1 capital ratio for the banks it supervised had risen from 14.4% at the start of 2020 to 15.2% at the end [3]Interview with Felix Hufeld. 3 June 2020. www.bafin.de . The revised rule was that dividends in 2021 should not exceed 15% of 2019-20 profits, or 20 bps of CET1 capital. Though the secretary of the Basel Committee, Carolyn Rogers, alarmed bankers (and some regulators alike) in November 2020 by arguing that the dividend ban should continue until the full extent of the covid hit to the economy was clear [4]Supervisory banking statistics. October 2020. www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu . That may take some time, as the pandemic rumbles on for longer than expected.

In other respects, however, the regulators were somewhat more helpful to the banks. The ECB implemented a series of relief measures, which were broadly paralleled by the Bank of England and others. They allowed, indeed encouraged banks to dip into their capital conservation buffers, and allowed some capital instruments which would not normally be counted towards pillar 2 requirements to be incorporated. The ECB revealed in January 2021 that nine banks, which would otherwise have fallen below its CET1 guidance, had taken advantage of that flexibility, though most have not needed to do so. The regulators also allowed the use of transitional IFRS 9 provisions, which somewhat reduced the procyclicality of the expected loss calculations. Banks could operate below the 100% liquidity coverage ratio until the end of 2021, and that may be extended. Furthermore, a series of other supervisory interventions were deferred or abandoned, notably the deadline for meeting the 2019 qualitative guidance.

But these transitional relief measures are specifically related to the crisis period, and there has been no suggestion from the ECB, or the Bank of England, that capital requirements will be relaxed in the longer term. Indeed the full implementation of Basel 3, to which the regulators are committed, would increase minimum capital for a number of institutions, putting further pressure on profitability, which is already challenged. As the ECB itself concludes: “Banks profitability and business model sustainability remain under pressure from the economic environment, low interest rates, excess capacity, low cost efficiency, and competition from banks and non-banks” [5]Quoted in the Financial Times. 17 November 2020. www.ft.com . They do not include high capital and liquidity requirements in that list of obstacles. While in the US there have been some signs of willingness to lighten capital requirements on small institutions in particular, there is no sign yet of a similar move in Europe.

The banks, while not requesting a major relaxation of the rules, have asked the ECB to rethink the remainder of the Basel 3 reforms, and invited the Commission to use its discretion to reduce the scale of the levy paid to the Single Resolution Fund. Both requests have so far been declined.

A recent report by the independent banking analyst at Autonomous has argued the capital rules for banks in the UK, and the same could certainly be said of banks in the Eurozone, are now arcane and in some respects dysfunctional. “The UK capital framework is creaking under the weight of its own complexity”, the author Christopher Cant maintains, and “the level of complexity is a deterrent for investors” [6]ECB supervisory priorities 2021. 28 January 2021. www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu . The stress testing arrangements are opaque, and there is still no clarity on the transitional arrangements for IFRS 9. There is uncertainty over the MREL and liquidity requirements. Overall, they conclude, “the scenario doesn’t exactly bode well for a rapid normalisation of dividends”.

There is another dimension of regulation, however, where change might be in prospect. For some time the banks have maintained that new digital competitors, whether small fintech start-ups or Bigtech giants, have benefited from lighter regulation in areas such as data usage and anti-money laundering, where banks seem to be held to higher standards. And there has been a bias towards promoting new competition, through forcing the opening up of banking relationships (open banking) and regulatory sandboxes, in which the regulators help new entrants to develop compliant business systems.

The response from regulators to date has been that the same activity is subject to the same regulation, and that most of these new entrants have chosen not to be banks, which brings obligations as well as rights.

There are signs that this line may be in the process of being rethought. A February 2021 paper [7]UK banks: creaky capital. Autonomous. 27 January 2021. www.autonomous.com by Fernando Restoy, of the Financial Stability Institute, a think tank linked to the Bank for International Settlements in Basel, questioned the current approach. Restoy notes that the ‘same activity, same regulation’ mantra is not accurate, and that incumbent banks have specific entity-based prudential and other obligations which do not facilitate a level playing field. He argues that ‘the growth potential of fintech and big tech companies could be, in part, the consequence of lighter regulatory requirements’. He goes on ‘regulation specific to banks entails higher compliance costs and can therefore put them at a competitive disadvantage’.

The policy implications of his analysis are intriguing. His main point is that while banks have argued that regulation should be activity-based to promote a level playing field, that may well not be the consequence, and that fintechs may ‘generate concrete threats to relevant policy objectives such as market integrity or stability or fair competition’. Those threats may create a case for entity-based regulation of these new entrants, which would achieve a better balance of policy objectives, and would in practice level what is now a very bumpy playing field.

It is too early to say whether this argument will influence key decision-makers in the European Commission, or elsewhere in the Tower of Basel for example, but the implications could be far-reaching.

It is possible, too, that payments initiatives led by central banks themselves will alter the competitive landscape. The most recent survey by the BIS shows that 86% of the central banks surveyed are working on their own digital currencies [8]Fintech regulation: how to achieve a level playing field. Fernando Restoy. February 2021. Financial Stability Institute Occasional Paper No. 17. www.bis.org . The gauntlet thrown down by Facebook’s Libra initiative, now dubbed Diem, has stung the central banks into a response. Depending on the nature of the response CBDCs could disintermediate commercial banks or strengthen them. The ECB has [9]Digital Currencies and the future of the monetary system. Remarks by Agustin Carstens, General Manager, Bank for International Settlements. Hoover Institution policy seminar. Basel 27 January 2021. … Continue reading suggested in a consultation paper that individuals should hold digital euros through their accounts at private sector banks. If they maintain that view commercial banks could find their position in the payments landscape reinforced.

So the incumbent banks robustness and resilience in the Covid crisis has pleased regulators, and there are signs that the nature of desirable competition may be under review. But in the long run customer preferences will be decisive. Has their performance paid dividends with customers?

 

2. Flight to Safety

The key lending support schemes for businesses affected by the covid crisis were backed by governments in various ways. But while that was true, lenders still needed the balance sheet strength to participate in the schemes. For the most part they took the view that, at least in the early stages, they would lend only to existing clients. Performing new ‘know your customer’ checks was almost impossible in the timescales involved. So businesses which had moved their business to challenger banks or peer to peer lenders faced a problem if those lenders could not extend their facilities rapidly.

Some of the new lenders – Tide is an example in the UK – were able to participate fully in the government schemes, but others had less balance sheet flexibility. There are no reliable data on how many companies were affected by the inability of their principal bank to extend further credit, but there is some anecdotal evidence. Alan McIntyre, head of Accenture’s global banking practice, commented, “Part of the fintech challenge is that in times of uncertainty and stress, traditional banks are seen as a safe haven. This partly reflects a flight to safety, as people hew closer to institutions with long track records that they judge more likely to survive an economic downturn” [10]Report on a digital euro. European Central Bank. October 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu.

How significant has this factor become? Have new competitors in the banking sector in fact lost share to the larger incumbents. The answer is not clearcut. A research note by Jeffries in July 2020 entitled “Will Corona kill the Digital-Only Challenger? [11]Alan McIntyre. Quoted in Tearsheet. 14 August 2020. www.tearsheet.com ”, focussing on the UK market, argued that “digital engagement has inflected back into the hands of large incumbents in the era of coronavirus”. Their evidence to back this claim showed that the rates at which customers were installing apps from large and small banks had begun to change in 2020. For some time the app share of challenger banks had been rising, but the trend changed in early 2020. The significance of this change of trend is disputed. Starling, a strong digital challenger, said “we simply do not recognise the picture outlined in this report”. It may also simply reflect an improvement in the digital offerings of the larger banks, rather than a lack of confidence in the stability of new entrants.

 

3. Competition

There are signs, however, that the competitive environment for the big banks may have become a little less intense. Some fintechs have struggled in the new landscape. While finance has remained available to fund the growth of the most promising and competitive, the implied equity valuations have fallen when new money has been raised. Some have withdrawn from markets in which they are marginal players. N 26 pulled out of the UK, for example, but the cost advantages of the new entrants which focus on payment services, with up to date technology and without the cost drag of large branch networks, remain strong. Both Monzo and Revolut have continued to grow their customer base, though profitability remains elusive.

And the societal and behavioural changes driven by lockdown restrictions may work to their advantage. Deloitte point out that “as social distancing has taken hold worldwide, there has been tremendous growth in the use of digital services and e-commerce [12]Will Corona kill the digital-only challenger? Jeffries equity research. July 2020. www.jeffries.com ”. The footfall in traditional bank branches has necessarily fallen, which may have the effect of reducing brand loyalty in the medium term. The number of bank branches in the EU fell by over 6% in 2019: the fall is likely to have been sharper in 2020. Deloitte’s conclusion, which is plausible, is that “an important outcome of COVID-19 for fintechs may well be the continued acceleration of partnerships with financial institutions, which can offer the benefits of capital, distribution access, and compliance infrastructure, but often lack highly sought-after digital solutions”.

Different considerations apply to the Bigtech companies, Apple, Google, Amazon and Facebook in particular. They can hardly be described as financially challenged. Their balance sheets are stronger than those of any major bank, and their market valuations are of a different order. Amazon’s market capitalisation in early February 2021 was around $1.7 trillion, compared to JP Morgan’s $420 billion.

The challengers and peer to peer lenders who offer credit face a different challenge. They will almost certainly experience a credit environment which will be far more hostile than they have encountered hitherto. I suspect some may be crushed under the wheels of an unforgiving credit cycle. There will be an element of chance in who survives and who does not. Those which had completed a funding round shortly before the crisis hit may well have the resources to ride out the storm. Others, who need more capital to grow (and many are still loss-making) will find new money harder to raise except on terms which may constrain their growth ambitions. Investors in peer to peer lenders have found it difficult to access their cash, with waits of several months at some providers [13]Beyond COVID-19. New opportunities for fintech companies. Deloitte Center for Financial Services. January 2021. www.deloitte.com . That is likely to constrain growth in the future as investors will be far more reluctant to fund them if they fear their money is locked up. Some have sought wholesale funding to replace the retail funds, which may guarantee short-term survival but will put pressure on margins in the longer run.

A continued shake-out in the challenger bank and peer to peer sectors seems very likely. But will that be enough to alter the competitive dynamics of the European banking sector, and return it to acceptable levels of profitability, with share prices at or above book value?

 

Are banks now stronger?

Generalisations about the prospects for European banks are hazardous. Some large banks, especially those in Scandinavia, have remained acceptably profitable throughout the last difficult decade. They have achieved low cost-income ratios, maintained strong market positions and innovated successfully and repeatedly. Their reputations have remained strong, too, though in some cases tarnished through money-laundering problems. But, on average, large European banks have found it difficult to earn their cost of capital.

Looking forward, the most decisive influence will be the level and shape of the yield curve. That in turn will be influenced ultimately by the supply of and demand for investment funds. The central banks will not raise rates to rescue the profitability of the banking sector. Negative interest rates will make the problem more severe for banks, as it is both technically and presentationally difficult to charge negative rates to retail customers who have the opportunity to switch money holdings into cash. The ECB has tried to mitigate the impact of very low rates on the banks, with mixed success. They may continue to do so, as may the Bank of England if it also imposes negative rates. In February 2021 they asked the banks to prepare for that eventuality.

When challenged about the viability of the banking sector the ECB typically points to a lack of concentration, and high costs, suggesting that many of the remedies lie in the hands of the banks themselves. In 2016, for example, Mario Draghi said: “Overcapacity in some national banking sectors, and the ensuing intensity of competition, exacerbates this squeeze on margins [14]Peer to peer lending. Martin Lewis and Amy Roberts. 4 February 2021. www.moneysavingexpert.com ”. How valid is this argument, and what scope is there for further bank consolidation in Europe?

On a conventional definition, concentration in EU banking seems quite high. On average the top 5 banks per country have 65% of the market as defined by balance sheet size, with the range running from 28 to 97% [15]Speech by Mario Draghi . Frankfurt 22 September 2016. www.reuters.com . But the ECB have attempted a more sophisticated analysis to try to determine what we mean by overcapacity in the banking sector, and where it is present.The research [16]EU structural financial indicators: end of 2019. 8 June 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu identifies three overlapping definitions of overcapacity. The first is size, measured by bank assets as a percentage of GDP, and as a percentage of the whole financial sector. The second is the intensity of competition. As proxies they use the number of banks per 100,000 inhabitants, the concentration ratio and also measures of Net Interest Margin and Return on Assets. The third dimension they call “Infrastructure/efficiency” which includes a basket of measures such as the number of people per bank branch, customer deposits per branch and total assets per bank employee. From these three components they construct a composite indicator of overcapacity.

The methodology may be open to criticism, and the composite measure involves a degree of subjective judgement on the weights to be attached to individual factors. But the results are intuitively reasonable. They show that those Scandinavian countries where returns on equity, and price to book ratios, are healthy, show low volumes of overcapacity. At the other end of the European scale Germany, Austria, France and Italy have relatively more overcapacity. As the authors point out, ‘the banking systems of these countries are often characterised by the traditionally strong role of savings and cooperative banks, and, thus, a high number of banks, lower degree of concentration and an extensive physical infrastructure”.

Where that is the principal reason for overcapacity it is not easy for private sector banks to solve the problem Draghi identified. There are countries where consolidation is possible, and there has been some recent activity in Spain and Italy, but the analysis suggests that different approaches are needed in different countries. In some cases progress can be made through conventional efficiency improvements, such as branch closures. In others exit of some players may be needed. These are controversial and time-consuming changes.

Pre-crisis, the ECB’s solution was threefold: reductions in Non-Performing Loans, for those still with high stocks of such loans, in-market consolidation by weak-performing small banks and a combination of bank-level restructuring and cross-border M&A activity for poor performers among the large banks [17]Overcapacities in banking: measurements, trends and determinants. Sandor Gardo and Benjamin Klaus. Occasional Paper No. 236. November 2019, www.ecb.europa.eu . The first option now looks harder to achieve. In-market consolidation is difficult but not impossible and the crisis may give those efforts a boost, as we have seen in some cases. But significant cross-border consolidation looks as far off as ever, for cultural, political and regulatory reasons. In 2018 bank M&A activity in Europe was lower than at any time this century [18]Euro area bank profitability. Where can consolidation help? Deislava Andreeva, Maciej Grodzicki, Csaba More and Alessio Reghezza. ECB Financial Stability Review November 2019. www.ecb.europa.eu . Andrea Enria, the Chairman of the ECB’s Supervisory Board, has acknowledged that countries are still ringfencing liquidity and capital at the national level, which means that limited benefits emerge from operating across borders.

 

Conclusions

One conclusion from this review might be that nothing fundamental has changed.

Banks with high costs and weak positions in slow-growing markets remain as challenged as before. Indeed the likely resurgence of NPLs, which had been declining for several years, will make their dilemma sharper.

The interest rate prospect, from a bank’s perspective at least, has become even more pessimistic. The prospect of strongly positive real interest rates has retreated further into the future.
The attractiveness of new digital competitors in the payments arena, unburdened by the legacy costs of unwieldy technology stacks, remains strong.

But that conclusion does require some qualification. Politicians and regulators have seen that the financial re-regulation they oversaw since 2008 has indeed delivered a banking sector which is robust, even in a sudden and unparalleled economic crisis delivered by the pandemic. Over time, that will reduce the pressure for ever higher capital ratios, which were in prospect before the crisis hit. They have seen that strong bank balance sheets are a highly valuable asset at times when the private sector needs credit and liquidity support on a massive scale, and that bank systems can deliver sharply higher volumes of activity very quickly. As a result, the reputation of banks, and trust in bankers, have risen, after a long period in which the latter were languishing near the bottom of the trust league, along with politicians and journalists. That reputational benefit does not translate into an enhanced return on equity in the short term but it will have a value over time.
We have also seen that non-bank credit provision can have fragile foundations, causing some business customers to appreciate the value of a solid banking relationship more. That may also translate into business opportunities in the longer run.

But the pressures on banks to reduce cost income ratios, to focus on business areas where they have a defensible market position, to control NPLs and to upgrade their technology to compete effectively with new competitors will remain intense. Covid is not going to offer the banks a ‘get out of gaol card’ but some of the more fanciful predictions of the death of banking may need to be revised. In 1997 Bill Gates said “We need banking. We don’t need banks any more” [19]Quoted in “Bye Bye banks” www.jessleitch.co . It is fortunate for the global economy that this is one of his predictions which did not come true.

Footnotes[+]

Footnotes
↑1 Chair of the Natwest Group. Professor at Sciences Po, Paris.
↑2 Dividend payouts and share buybacks of global banks. ECB Financial Stability Review. May 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu
↑3 Interview with Felix Hufeld. 3 June 2020. www.bafin.de
↑4 Supervisory banking statistics. October 2020. www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu
↑5 Quoted in the Financial Times. 17 November 2020. www.ft.com
↑6 ECB supervisory priorities 2021. 28 January 2021. www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu
↑7 UK banks: creaky capital. Autonomous. 27 January 2021. www.autonomous.com
↑8 Fintech regulation: how to achieve a level playing field. Fernando Restoy. February 2021. Financial Stability Institute Occasional Paper No. 17. www.bis.org
↑9 Digital Currencies and the future of the monetary system. Remarks by Agustin Carstens, General Manager, Bank for International Settlements. Hoover Institution policy seminar. Basel 27 January 2021. www.bis.org
↑10 Report on a digital euro. European Central Bank. October 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu
↑11 Alan McIntyre. Quoted in Tearsheet. 14 August 2020. www.tearsheet.com
↑12 Will Corona kill the digital-only challenger? Jeffries equity research. July 2020. www.jeffries.com
↑13 Beyond COVID-19. New opportunities for fintech companies. Deloitte Center for Financial Services. January 2021. www.deloitte.com
↑14 Peer to peer lending. Martin Lewis and Amy Roberts. 4 February 2021. www.moneysavingexpert.com
↑15 Speech by Mario Draghi . Frankfurt 22 September 2016. www.reuters.com
↑16 EU structural financial indicators: end of 2019. 8 June 2020. www.ecb.europa.eu
↑17 Overcapacities in banking: measurements, trends and determinants. Sandor Gardo and Benjamin Klaus. Occasional Paper No. 236. November 2019, www.ecb.europa.eu
↑18 Euro area bank profitability. Where can consolidation help? Deislava Andreeva, Maciej Grodzicki, Csaba More and Alessio Reghezza. ECB Financial Stability Review November 2019. www.ecb.europa.eu
↑19 Quoted in “Bye Bye banks” www.jessleitch.co

Filed Under: 2021.1

The European Banking Union: Challenges Ahead

March 2, 2016 by Howard Davies

This Q&A Section discusses the evolution of Multinational Banking in Europe, focusing on the halt to the integration process that occurred after the recent financial crises. How could institutions learn from the past and revitalize the integration process?

From 2015.3 - Question and Answers

CURRENT ISSUE

Central Banks Digital Currencies

READ MORE

European Economy
Banks, Regulation, and the Real Sector

Publisher
Associazione Centro Studi Luca d'Agliano

Copyright © 2025 · Author Pro Theme on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in

This website uses cookies to improve your experience. We'll assume you're ok with this, but you can opt-out if you wish.Accept Read More
Privacy & Cookies Policy

Privacy Overview

This website uses cookies to improve your experience while you navigate through the website. Out of these, the cookies that are categorized as necessary are stored on your browser as they are essential for the working of basic functionalities of the website. We also use third-party cookies that help us analyze and understand how you use this website. These cookies will be stored in your browser only with your consent. You also have the option to opt-out of these cookies. But opting out of some of these cookies may affect your browsing experience.
Necessary
Always Enabled
Necessary cookies are absolutely essential for the website to function properly. This category only includes cookies that ensures basic functionalities and security features of the website. These cookies do not store any personal information.
Non-necessary
Any cookies that may not be particularly necessary for the website to function and is used specifically to collect user personal data via analytics, ads, other embedded contents are termed as non-necessary cookies. It is mandatory to procure user consent prior to running these cookies on your website.
SAVE & ACCEPT