On the determinants of non-performing loans
A first comprehensive investigation of NPLs in Europe is the IMF staff discussion note (2015). It provides figures for EU and the US and discusses why the secondary market for non-performing loans (NPLs hereafter) is underdeveloped in EU compared to the US market. It also illustrates the impact of NPL on growth which are more relevant for countries that rely mainly on bank financing. Many NPLs reduce profitability, increase funding costs and limit bank capital. This in turn reduces the supply of credit with negative consequences on growth.
The level of NPL were relatively stable until the beginning of the financial crisis in 2008. Afterwards, the quality of banks’ portfolio has progressively declined. The response from the governments and central banks to deal with impaired bank assets, recapitalizing and / or restructuring troubled banks, and several actions to inject liquidity into the banking system was significant in Europe and the US (Avgouleas and Goodhart, 2015, 2016).[1]See the issue 2016. 2 of this journal for more information about bank resolution policies implemented in Europe and the U.S. Nowadays, the level of NPLs remains high and undermines the stability of the European banking sector (Aiyar et al., 2017). Unlike other industries, the impact of a failure of one bank can spread to others, causing a chain effect and jeopardizing the whole sector at home or globally (Demirguç-Kunt, 1989; Barr et al., 1994).
A wide range of reasons may have generated the NPLs problem in Europe including the economic recession, the sovereign debt crisis, government support provided to the financial institutions in the early stage of the crisis, and managerial practices of some banks (Anastasiou et al., 2016; Chiorazzo et al., 2017; Louzis et al., 2012; Jassaud and Kang, 2015; Salas and Saurina, 2002).
The European Investment Bank (2014) and IMF (2015) have shown that Euro Area banks with higher NPLs ratios lend less than other banks, ceteris paribus. Furthermore, these effects tend to affect SMEs more significantly because these firms are more dependent on bank finance. The relevance of macroeconomic dynamics reflects the endogeneity issue that undermines the identification of the adequate transmission channel of NPLs on lending supply: NPLs rise in economies and countries affected by economic stagnation, and consequently (i) creditworthiness is deteriorated and (ii) the demand for lending also tend to weaken (Accornero et al., 2017). Similarly, several studies demonstrate that both NPLs and loan loss provisions ratio -two indicators of the quality of banks’ loan portfolio- have a negative correlation with bank lending supply (Balgova et al., 2016; Bending et al., 2014; Cucinelli, 2015). Importantly, deterioration of public finances places a ‘ceiling’ on the market evaluation of credibility of domestic banks, and therefore they are hard-pressed for liquidity (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2010). As a result, banks are unable to provide new lending and debtors cannot refinance their debts.
On non-performing loans and moral hazard problems
A rapid credit expansion is considered as one of the most important causes of troubled loans. Agency problems between shareholders and managers may arise if the formers are interested in business growth which might imply promotion, more power or better status within the organization (Williamson, 1963).
The distinctive features of the banking sector and the efforts of financial institutions to improve efficiency and risk management are found to influence the evolution of NPLs (Durán and Lozano, 2015; Zhang et al., 2016). Berger and De Young (1997) demonstrated that poor managerial skills in credit scoring, appraisal for pledged collateral, and monitoring borrowers may increase the volume of NPL in the future, the so-called bad management hypothesis.[2]See Podpiera and Weill (2008) for similar results. Additionally, banks should face a trade-off between allocating resources for underwriting and monitoring loans, and measured cost efficiency. The reduction in efforts to ensure high quality loans will make banks more cost-efficient but increasing NPLs in the long term, the so-called skimping hypothesis (Luozis et al., 2012).[3]Bebchuk and Spamann (2010) and Bebchuk et al. (2010) show that the CEO’s system of incentives focussed on short-term results contributed to increasing banks’ risk-taking as of the beginning of … Continue reading From the regulator’s point of view, NPLs ratio is a useful indicator to measure the extent of moral hazard behaviour in order to avoid potential financial instability (Zhang et al., 2016).
Quality portfolio of banks may endogenously induce further risk-taking. Prudential banks would be more cautious when taking on increasing NPLs. However, NPLs above a threshold may incentivize banks to shift risks (Bernanke and Gelter, 1986). Thus, banks showing a higher level of troubled loan portfolio are more likely to assume higher level of risk in the future (Bowman and Malmendier, 2015; Buchner et al., forthcoming; Eisdorfer 2008; Koudstaal and Wijnbergen, 2012). Accordingly, Bruche and Llobet’s (2011) theoretical model predicts that efficiency gains from having bad loans foreclosed allows banks with a relatively proportion of NPLs to gamble to increase their chances of recovery.[4]The optimal contract involves making banks with a small proportion of bank loans foreclose (Bruche and Llobet, 2011).
The ‘too-big-too-fail’ (TBTF hereafter) banks represent another channel to origin NPLs. Under the TBTF presumption, banks are expected to increase their leverage excessively and extend loans to low quality borrowers, being subsequently affected by adverse selection problems (Stern and Feldman, 2004). Thus, moral hazard problems might become more relevant in case TBTF banks take advantage of their higher market power, or they expect to be bailed out in case of capital shortage (Boyd and Graham, 1998; Nier and Baumann, 2006). Consequently, bank risk-taking may be also connected to the characteristics of the government’s reaction function due to banks can be members of a deposit insurance network ex ante to avoid depositors runs or getting bailouts from the governments, and ex post if deemed TBTF or ‘too-many-to-fail’ (Ashraf, 2017).[5]Dam and Koetter (2012) shows that the expectation of a bail-out, rather than actual bail-outs, may be a precursor of moral hazard. Cukierman (2013) shows that the decision of bailing out financial … Continue reading
On the theoretical fundamentals of the proposals to deal with NPLs
The debate about government interventions to reduce the weight of NPLs in several advanced and emerging economies is still alive (Ahamed and Mallick, 2017). The creation of a pan-European bad bank or an asset management company (AMC hereafter) has been proposed as a possible solution by several voices (Goodhart and Avgouleas 2015, 2016; Enria, 2016, 2017; Hellwig, 2017). This argument is recently reinforced by Arner et al. (2017) whom demonstrate that in a context of systemic financial crisis, a combination of balance sheet restructuring and the use of AMCs to deal with NPLs is often the best choice.[6]Similar arguments are found in Hryckiewicz (2014). Despite the importance of this phenomenon, the repercussions of establishing an AMC is referred in the policy literature, normally based in empirical evidence from countries which implemented previously these measures such as Spain, Ireland or China, amongst others (Arner et al., 2017; Bending et al., 2014; Zhang et al., 2016).
Luchetta and Parigi’s (2016) theoretical model analyses the rational of an AMC and under which conditions it is socially acceptable. They argue that segregating legacy activities in an AMC might eliminate underinvestment, but on the other hand, it might also add value because it gambles on the resurrection of the segregated entities. This contribution explains why risk transfer through the AMC is valuable for shareholders. However, risk transfer happens at the expenses of debt holders, so shareholders may segregate activities beyond the social optimal. Likewise, Shi (2004) analyses the reforms implemented in China which had registered a long-standing problem with NPLs. The argument is that during the transition period, the government allowed banks for soft-budget constraints to both state-owned enterprises and state-owned banks. Consequently, capital injections could have induced moral hazard because banks might have had incentived to make loans to troubled firms due to the government’s implicit guarantees (Jiang et al., 2013).
Securitization involves the legal or economic transfer of assets or obligations by an originating institution to a third party, typically a special purpose vehicle (SPV hereafter). Later on, the SPV issues asset-back securities or other structured finance securities such as mortgage-backed securities, collateralised debt obligations or whole business securitisation, representing claims against specific assets (Agostino and Mazzuca, 2011).[7]At time of writing this note, the Italian government is in the process of creating a state-owned AMC SPV to accelerate the transfer of NPLs without violating the rules of the BBRD. Furthermore, large … Continue reading According to the funding hypothesis, banks securitize in order to obtain funding channels as alternative to deposits (Greenbaum and Thakor, 1987; De Marzo, 2005; De Marzo and Duffie, 1999). Additionally, the specialization hypothesis predicts that banks securitize in order to increase their level of specialisation -i.e. in loan origination activities- thus increasing their economic performance. By doing so, banks decompose the traditional lending process intro more sophisticated activities of originating, servicing, guaranteeing, and funding (Greenbaum, 1986). Finally, the regulatory capital arbitrage (RCA hereafter) hypothesis argue that banks would securitize if they can achieve RCA by transferring to others their best quality assets (Calem and LaCour-Little, 2004). Agostino and Mazzuca (2011) find for an Italian sample of banks that NPLs securitization seems to have been affected to a lesser extent by a funding motivation and to have been conditioned by a specialization incentive, whereas the RCA motivation is apparently irrelevant. During an initial step, banks may have used securitization to clean up their balance sheets, thus causing operations to be collateralized mainly by NPLs. Nevertheless, banks also collateralized assets other than NPLs and residential mortgages demonstrating that securitization may provide an alternative to the traditional funding channels.
Recently, Bruno et al. (2016) advocate that a securitization scheme can offer interesting yields for the senior and mezzanine tranches, whilst offering simultaneously a similar price for the stock of NPLs close to the book value. Hence, the issue can be reduced to a manageable volume in two categories: (i) the loss immediately recorded by banks which might not force them to increase capital, and (ii) the risk accepted by investors of the junior tranches.
Other policy interventions
Several recent papers (Philippon and Skreta 2012, Tirole 2012, Fuchs and Skrzypacz 2013) have clarified that public authorities can efficiently allow for a jumpstart of the market restoring confidence and liquidity. These activities can be particularly effective when buyers and sellers significantly disagree over the value of the assets to trade and related collateral. For example, subsidizing current exchanges and taxing future ones can significantly improve the mix of quality of tradable assets inducing early market entry of owners of better assets. There is in fact a tendency for good assets owners to wait for hopefully higher prices and conversely for low quality assets owners to populate the market immediately.
This adverse mix clearly depresses buyers’ expectations and increases the bid-ask gap. A policy of current trade subsidies and future trade taxes may affect the intertemporal trade off, reduces the bid-ask gap and increases exchange prices, thus inducing even more trade.
Accornero, M., Alessandri, P., Carpinelli, L., and Sorrentino, A.M. (2017). Non-performing loans and the supply of bank credit: Evidence from Italy. Bank of Italy, Occasional Paper No. 374. Available at: https://www.bancaditalia.it/pubblicazioni/qef/2017-0374/index.html?com.dotmarketing.htmlpage.language=1
Agostino, M., and Mazzuca, M. (2011). Empirical investigation of securitisation drivers: the case of Italian banks. European Journal of Finance, 17, 623-648.
Ahamed, M.M., and Mallick, S. (2017). Does regulatory forbearance matter for bank stability? Evidnece from creditors’ perspective. Journal of Financial Stability, 28, 163-180.
Aiyar, S., Bergthaler, W., Garrido, J.M., Ilyna, A., Jobst, A., Kang, K., Kovtun, D., Monaghan, D., and Moretti, M. (2015). A strategy for resolving Europe’s problem loans. IMF Staff Discussion Note. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2015/sdn1519.pdf
Anastasiou, D., Louri, H., Tsionas, E.G. (2017). Non-Performing Loans in the Euro Area: Are Core-Periphery Banking Markets Fragmented? SSRN Working Paper. Available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2868777
Antzoulatos, A.A., and Tsoumas, C. (2014). Institutions, moral hazard, and expected government support of banks. Journal of Financial Stability, 15, 161-171.
Arner, D.W., Avgouleas, E., and Gibson, E. (2017). Overstanding moral hazard: lessons from two decades of banking crises. University of Hong Kong Faculty of Law Research Paper No. 2017/003. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2929574
Ashraf, B.N. (2017). Political institutions and bank risk-taking behavior. Journal of Financial Stability, 29, 13-35.
Avgouleas, E., and Goodhart, C. (2015). Critical reflections on bail-ins. Journal of Financial Regulation, 1, 3-29.
Avgouleas, E., and Goodhart, C. (2016). An anatomy of bank bail-ins – Why the Eurozone needs a fiscal backstop for the banking sector. European Economy – Banks, Regulation, and the Real Sector, 2016.2, 75-90. Available at: https://european-economy.eu/leading-articles/an-anatomy-of-bank-bail-ins-why-the-eurozone-needs-a-fiscal-backstop-for-the-banking-sector/
Balgova, M., Nies, M., and Plekhanov, A. (2016). The economic impact of reducing non-performing loans. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development Working Paper, 193. Available at: http://www.ebrd.com/publications/working-papers/economic-impact.html
Barr, R.S., Seiford, L.M., and Siems, T.F. (1994). Forecasting bank failure: a non-parametric frontier estimation approach. Recherches Economiques de Louvain/Louvain Economic Review, 60, 417–429.
Bebchuk, L., and Sparmann, H. (2010). Regulatory bankers’ pay. Georgetown Law Journal, 98, 247-287.
Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., Sparman, H. (2010). The wages of the failure: Executive compensation at Bear Sterns and Lehman 2000 – 2008. Yale Journal on Regulation, 27, 257-282.
Bending, T., Berndt, M., Betz, F., Brutscher, P., Nelvin, O., Revoltella, D., Slacik, T., Wolski, M., (2014) Unlocking lending in Europe. European Investment Bank. Available at: http://www.eib.org/attachments/efs/economic_report_unlocking_lending_in_europe_en.pdf
Berger A., and De Young, R. (1997). Problem loans and cost efficiency in commercial banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 21, 849-870.
Bernanke, B., and Gelter, M. (1986). Banking and macroeconomic equilibrium. Princeton University. Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs.
Bowman, C.H.S., and Malmendier, U. (2015). Does a bank’s history affect its risk taking? American Economic Review, 105, 321-325.
Boyd, J.H., and De Nicolò, G. (2005). The theory of bank risk-taking and competition revisited. Journal of Finance, 60, 1329-1343.
Boyd, J.H., De Nicolò, G., and Jalal, A.M. (2006). Bank risk-taking and competition revisited: New theory and new evidence. Working paper series 06/297, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=20126.0
Boyd, J.H., and Graham, S.L. (1998). Consolidation in US banking: Implications for efficiency and risk. Bank Mergers and Acquisitions, 3, 113–135.
Bruche, M., and Llobet, G. (2011). Walking wounded or living dead? Making banks foreclose bad banks. LSE Discussion Paper No. 675. Available at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/fmg/workingPapers/discussionPapers/DP675_2011_WalkingWounded.pdf
Buchner, A., and Wagner, N. (2017). Rewarding risk-taking or skills? The case of private equity fund managers. Journal of Banking and Finance, forthcoming.
Bruno, B., Lusignani, G., and Onado, M. (2017). A securitisation scheme for resolving Europe’s problem loans. Mimeo.
Calem, P. S. and LaCour-Little, M. (2004). Risk-based capital requirements for mortgage loans. The Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 647–72.
Chiorazzo, V. D’Apice, V., and Franco, F., Francesco, M., and Pierluigi, M. (2017). NPLs in Europe: The Role of Systematic and Idiosyncratic Factors. SSRN Working Paper. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2903851
Cucinelli, D. (2015). The Impact of Non-performing Loans on Bank Lending Behavior: Evidence from the Italian Banking Sector. Eurasian Journal of Business and Economics, 8, 59-71.
Cukierman, A. (2013). Monetary policy and institutions before, during, and after the global financial crisis. Journal of Financial Stability, 9, 373-384.
Dam, L., and Koeter, M. (2012). Bank bailouts and moral hazard: Evidence from Germany. Review of Financial Studies, 25, 2343-2380.
De Marzo, P. M. (2005). The pooling and tranching of securities: a model of informed intermediation. Review of Financial Studies, 18, 1–35.
De Marzo, P. M., and Duffie, D. (1999). A liquidity-based model of security design. Econometrica, 67, 65–99.
Demirguç-Kunt, A. (1989). Deposit-institution failures: a review of empirical literature. Economic Review, 4, 2–18.
Dobson, W., and Kashyap, A.K. (2006). The contradiction in China’s gradualist banking reforms. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 103–162.
Durán, M.A., and Lozano-Vivas, A. (2015). Moral Hazard and the financial structure of the Banks. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 34, 28-40.
Eisdorfer, A. (2008). Empirical evidence of risk shifting in financially distressed banks. Journal of Finance, 63, 609-637.
Enria, A. (2016). Financial markets 2.0. R(evolution): Rebooting the European banking sector. Speech delivered at the 7th FMA Supervisory Conference. Vienna, 5th October 2016. European Banking Authority. Available at: http://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/1606077/Andrea+Enria’s+speech+at+the+7th+FMA+Supervisory+Conference+-+05+October+2016.pdf
Enria, A (2017). The EU banking sector – risk and recovery. A single market perspective. European Banking Authority. Available at: https://www.esm.europa.eu/sites/default/files/2017_01_30_-_esm_risk_and_adjustment_at_eu_banks.pdf
European Investment Bank, (2014) “Unlocking lending in Europe,” available at: http://www.eib.org/infocentre/publications/all/unlocking-lending-in-europe.htm
Fu, Y., Lee, S.C., Xu, L., and Zurbruegg, R., 2015. The effectiveness of capital regulation on bank behavior in China. International Review of Finance, 15, 321-345.
Fuchs, W., and Skrzypacz, A. (2013) Costs and Benefits of Dynamic Trading in a Lemons Market. Stanford GSB Research Paper Series # 2133. August 2013.
Fuchs, William, Aniko O., and Andrzej Skrzypacz (2015) “Transparency and Distressed Sales under Asymmetric Information.” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1986.
Greenbaum, S.I. (1986). Securitization, asset quality and regulatory reform. BRC Working Paper, no. 147, Northwestern University.
Greenbaum, S.I., and Thakor, A.V. (1987). Bank funding modes. Securitization versus deposits. Journal of Banking and Finance, 11, 379–401.
IMF (2015) “Euro area policies, selected issues: policy options for tackling non-performing loans in the euro area.” Available at https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2015/cr15205.pdf
Hellwig, M. (2017). Carving out legacy assets: a successful tool for bank restructuring? Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2017/3. Available at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/IDAN/2017/587399/IPOL_IDA(2017)587399_EN.pdf
Hryckiewicz, A. (2014). What do we know about the impact of government interventions in the banking sector? An assessment of various bailout programs on bank behaviour. Journal of Banking and Finance, 46, 246-265.
Jassaud, N., and Kang, K. (2015). A Strategy for Developing a Market for Nonperforming Loans in Italy. IMF Working Paper WP/15/24. Available at: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/A-Strategy-for-Developing-a-Market-for-Nonperforming-Loans-in-Italy-42689
Jensen, M.C., and Mecklin, W.H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360.
Jiang, C., Yao, S., and Feng, G. (2013). Bank ownership, privatization, and performance: Evidence from a transition country. Journal of Banking and Finance, 37, 3364 – 3372.
Koudstaal, M., and Wijnbergen, S. (2012). On risk, leverage and banks: Do highly leveraged banks take on excessive risk? Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper. Available at: http://papers.tinbergen.nl/12022.pdf
Liu, H., Molyneux, P., and Wilson, J.O.S. (2013). Competition and stability in European banking: A regional analysis. Manchester School, 81, 176-201.
Louzis, D.P., Vouldis, A.T., Metaxas, V.L. (2012). Macroeconomic and bank-specific determinants of non-performing loans in Greece: A comparative study of mortgage, business and consumer loan portfolios. Journal of Banking and Finance, 36, 1012-1027.
Luchetta, M., and Parigi, B.M. (2016). Bad banks and underinvestment. CESifo Area Conference in Applied Microeconomics. Available at: https://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/events/Archive/conferences/2016/03/2016-03-18-am16-Gollier/Programme.html
Nier, E., and Baumann, U. (2006). Market discipline, disclosure and moral hazard in banking. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 15, 332–361.
Petersen, M.A., and Rajan, R. (1994). The benefits of lending relationships: Evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance, 49, 3-37.
Petersen, M.A., and Rajan, R. (1995). The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 407-443.
Philippon, T., and Skreta, V. (2012) Optimal Interventions in Markets with Adverse Selection, American Economic Review, 102, 1-28.
Pierre, C. (2013). Risk-shifting and the regulation of bank CEO’s compensation. Journal of Financial Stability, 9, 778-789.
Podpiera, J., and Weill, L. (2008). Bad luck or bad management? Emerging banking market experience. Journal of Financial Stability, 4, 135-148.
Reinhart, C.M., and Rogoff, K.S. (2010). Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review, 100, 573-578.
Salas, V., and Saurina, J. (2002). Credit risk in two institutional regimes: Spanish commercial and savings banks. Journal of Financial Services Research, 22, 203-224.
Shi, H.Q. (2004). On the endogenous nature of the non-performing loans of the state-owned bank of China: an analytical framework based on the dual soft-budget constraint theory. Journal of Financial Research (in Chinese) 6, 1–16.
Soerdamono, W., Machrouh, F., and Tarazi, A. (2013). Bank competition, crisis and risk taking: Evidence from emerging markets in Asia. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 23, 196–221.
Soerdamono, W., and Tarazi, A. (2016). Competition, financial intermediation, and riskiness of banks: Evidence from the Asia-Pacific region. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 52, 961-974.
Stern, G., and Feldman, R. (2004). Too big to fail: The hazard of banks bailouts. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.
Tan, Y., and Floros, C. (2013). Risk, capital and efficiency in Chinese banking. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 26, 378–393.
Tirole, J. (2012) Overcoming Adverse Selection: How Public Intervention Can Restore Market Functioning. American Economic Review, 102, 19-59.
Uhde, A., and Heimeshoff, U. (2009). Consolidation in banking and financial stability in Europe: Empirical Evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 1299-1311.
Williamson, O.E. (1963). Managerial discretion and business behavior. American Economic Review, 53, 1032-1057.
Zhang, D., Cai, J., Dickinson, D.G., Kutan, A.M. (2016). Non-performing loans, moral hazard and regulation of the Chinese commercial banking system. Journal of Banking and Finance, 63, 48-60.
Footnotes
↑1 | See the issue 2016. 2 of this journal for more information about bank resolution policies implemented in Europe and the U.S. |
---|---|
↑2 | See Podpiera and Weill (2008) for similar results. |
↑3 | Bebchuk and Spamann (2010) and Bebchuk et al. (2010) show that the CEO’s system of incentives focussed on short-term results contributed to increasing banks’ risk-taking as of the beginning of the financial crisis. Similarly, Pierre (2013) remarks that the CEO’s contract contributes to the excessive risk-taking higher than the social optimal level. |
↑4 | The optimal contract involves making banks with a small proportion of bank loans foreclose (Bruche and Llobet, 2011). |
↑5 | Dam and Koetter (2012) shows that the expectation of a bail-out, rather than actual bail-outs, may be a precursor of moral hazard. Cukierman (2013) shows that the decision of bailing out financial institutions depends on political ideologies and considerations. Similarly, Antzoulatos and Tsoumas (2014) argue that a substantial part of the expected bail-outs is attributed to a country’s institutional environment which might be associated with higher expectations of bail-outs. |
↑6 | Similar arguments are found in Hryckiewicz (2014). |
↑7 | At time of writing this note, the Italian government is in the process of creating a state-owned AMC SPV to accelerate the transfer of NPLs without violating the rules of the BBRD. Furthermore, large banks have set up AMC SPVs to dispose of NPLs off-balance sheet. The volume of these NPLs constitute 2-3 billion EUR and the advance is snail because of the NPL market was practically inexistent prior 2015 (Arner et al., 2017). |